Immigration and relative happiness

Steven Levitt points to a report by Kate Holton comparing self-reported happiness levels in different countries. Holton wrote:

Young people in developing nations are at least twice as likely to feel happy about their lives than their richer counterparts, a survey says. Indians are the happiest overall and Japanese the most miserable. According to an MTV Networks International (MTVNI) global survey that covered more than 5,400 young people in 14 countries, only 43 percent of the world’s 16- to 34-year-olds say they are happy with their lives. MTVNI said this figure was dragged down by young people in the developed world, including those in the United States and Britain where fewer than 30 percent of young people said they were happy with the way things were. . . . “The happier young people of the developing world are also the most religious,” the survey said. The MTVNI survey took six months to complete and resulted in the Wellbeing Index which compared the feelings of young people, based on their perceptions of how they feel about safety, where they fit into society and how they see their future. Young people from Argentina and South Africa came joint top in the list of how happy they were at 75 percent. The overall Wellbeing Index was more mixed between rich and poor. India came top followed by Sweden and Brazil came last.. . . The 14 countries included in the survey were Argentina, Brazil, China, Denmark, France, Germany, India, Indonesia, Japan, Mexico, South Africa, Sweden, the UK and the U.S.

Levitt basically says he doesn’t believe these results because, as he puts it,

Economists have a notion called “revealed preference.” By looking at people’s actions, you can infer how they feel. Applied to this MTV survey, if their measure of happiness or Wellbeing Index were meaningful, then I would expect that we would see a steady flow of unhappy young people from the United States and the United Kingdom immigrating to happy places like South Africa and Argentina and Wellbeing places like India.

History tells us that the flow of immigrants has always been and continues to be in the other direction, which to an economist, is the strongest evidence that whatever people are looking for, developed countries like the United States are where they are finding it.

I don’t know the details of the survey; for example, maybe the pollsters have more difficulty reaching unhappy people in some countries than others. But let’s assume that it’s doing a good job of getting people’s attitudes. Levitt writes that “people make many mistakes in forecasting what will or will not make them happy in the future,” but I don’t see why this invalidates survey responses about current happiness levels. If anything, it would suggest that emigrants to the U.S. are, possibly mistakenly, basing their decisions on estimates of future happiness (or maybe possibilities for their children). I would think that, from an economist’s perspective, it would be completely reasonable for a currently-happy person in India (say) to come to the U.S. in anticipation of future happiness for self and family. Even if this anticipation turns out to be wrong, the decision to emigrate will be based on the feelings at that time, not on their future happiness levels.

Beyond this, I wonder if Levitt is falling into a “Simpson’s paradox” trap of confusing within-group and between-group comparisons. The Indians who emigrate to America are not a random sample of Indians, and so it is possible for (a) Indians to be happier than Americans, and (b) Indian immigrants to become happier when moving to America. (But, given that people can make mistakes in forecasting their future happiness, I don’t know that (b) is true.)

To put it another way, I don’t plan to emigrate to India. But, even if the average Indian is happier than the average American, it doesn’t mean that I’d be happier if I were to emigrate. It’s the difference between correlation (the observed pattern of Indians and Americans) and causation (what would happen to an individual person if he or she were to move).

Anyway, I don’t mean to belabor the point, it’s just something I’d think an economist would be more aware of. Or, more likely, there’s another twist to the argument that I’m missing (for example, some reasoning about equilibria).

In summary . . .

It is a puzzle that people some countries (such as India) have higher average levels of self-reported happiness than people in the U.S., yet net immigration is from India to the U.S and not the reverse. There are several possible explanations for this puzzle, including:

1. The average happiness level in India is higher than that in the U.S., but it’s the unhappy Indians who are moving to the U.S.

2. Emigrants and immigrants are a small proportion of the population in both countries; thus, the happiness level of the people who move is essentially irrelevant to the calculation of average happiness in a country.

3. People move from India, expecting to be more happy in the U.S., but they are wrongly anticipating their future happiness. Actually, they won’t be so happy (on average) once they move.

4. People consciously decide to move to a less happy place, knowing they’ll probably be less happy, because they have goals other than immediate happiness (e.g., making a lot of money so they’ll be happy later, providing for their family, having a more exciting existence, seeing new places, …)

5. The surveys are not actually representative samples.

6. Immigration is largely about economic opportunities and family connections, and the average happiness level doesn’t really come into play. People will move to a less happy place if there are economic or family reasons to do so. (I should know, having chosen to go to college at MIT, and Levitt should know too, seeing as he teaches at the notoriously unhappy U of Chicago.)

It’s an interesting question, I think, and I’m not sure why Levitt was so quick to dismiss this sort of survey evidence. “Revealed preference” is a fine concept but preference isn’t always about happiness.

P.S. See here. This puts some weight on explanation #5 above!

9 thoughts on “Immigration and relative happiness

  1. I think (5) is probably right. You don't get the rural poor and street people into such surveys in developing countries. As we know happiness is largely about *relative* position in society any underrepresentation by the poor skews your results upwards.

  2. This is another example of economists playing another of their idiotic games, making unwarranted assumptions concerning things they apparently know little about. Places don't necessarily make people happy, so moving from a place where the average "happiness quotient" is low to one where it is higher won't necessarily make a person happier. If, as I suspect, connections — to family, friends, a culture, a religion — are what make people happy, then moving elsewhere will cut those ties, leading to less happiness wherever the person goes.

  3. Two points about what makes people happier, based on similar research.

    First, winning the lottery makes people happier, but only for a relatively short period of time (a couple of years, if my memory is correct). Most people would think that making the lottery would make them happier. That's why they pay to enter.

    Second, people without children are generally happier than people with children. I'm not sure if people planning to have children (a) realise that, and do it anyway – maybe that's what immigrants do – there are more aims in life than happiness; or (b) think it will make them happier.

  4. Jeremy,

    Having kids makes me much, much happier in a deep sense. However, I wouldn't be surprised if, being surveyed at random points in time, I am less happy, on average, than before I had kids. But I think the situation here is that my baseline level of happiness is so much higher, and if you ask me at any given moment how happy I am, I'm measuring myself against that baseline. Somehow it makes sense to me to say that I'm much much happier, even if I don't have a higher subjective happiness feeling, on average. Happiness isn't an additive quantity.

    So I suppose that's a possible explanation 7 to add above, if applied to the U.S./India comparison rather than the kids/kidless comparison.

    Winning the lottery . . . now, that would make me happy. But losing would make me unhappy. I find it mildly annoying that people use "winning the lottery" as an example for so many things, even though "losing the lottery" is so much more common.

  5. Does immigration make the host country happier is an even better question. If a country is not made happier by immigration, then why not stop it? It’s hard to tell, but Europeans seem to be made less happy by the wave of immigrants from North Africa. It’s hard to tell because most European countries (and Canada) have laws limiting what you can say or write about immigration or other religions. In the US, where we have more freedom of speech, people seem especially unhappy about immigration, particularly the illegal kind. On the other hand, many people might be made happier because they get the benefits of cheap labor, but then again it’s hard to tell because of the shadow costs of immigrants. So is the net happiness of US citizens increased or decreased by immigration? I don’t know, but the question is more interesting from a policy perspective.

  6. I'm not convinced that what we call happiness is a single thing. We could probably divide it into (at least) two concepts – local happiness "this instant" and general happiness. I think that having children relates more to the latter (or possibly towards a related concept like fulfilment).

    Beyond that you'd need a theoretical account of happiness to make sense of what's going on. The (naive) economic analysis is that happiness leads to inaction, but the some theories of emotion propose the opposite (with evidence in support). For example the broaden and build theory of emotion proposes that the evolutionaty function of positive emotions is to build resources – so you'd maybe expect happy people to plan for the future (whereas we know very unhappy people don't).

    The analysis of these patterns require a clear understanding of what's being measured and a clear theory of happiness to even begin to make sense of it.

    (This is not to trash revealed preference which is a useful concept – but I'm not sure it applies here).

  7. Thom: I agree about kids. That probably increases 'satisfaction' whilst decreasing 'joy', which you might think of as state and trait happiness.

    Andrew: I was only partially using winning the lottery as an example. It does make people happier in the short term (joy) but it doesn't increase happiness in the long term (satisfaction). What's interesting is that people are so convinced that it will make them happier (more satisfied) that they invest money, time and emotional energy into it.

  8. Happiness depend on 3 factors…universilism,materialism,spritualism….availability in one's individual life….and its relative aspect of living . So for a particular indian if he moves to U.S that does not mean he will be less happy there or more happy there….so far so much…

Comments are closed.